Fact Sheet

Fact Sheet: Toward a Robust Competition Policy

The rise of firms earning monopolistic returns calls for new policy measures to reduce barriers to entry and increase competition.

The New York Stock Exchange building stands in the financial district of New York City, March 2019. (Getty/Drew Angerer)
The New York Stock Exchange building stands in the financial district of New York City, March 2019. (Getty/Drew Angerer)

See also: Toward a Robust Competition Policy” by Marc Jarsulic, Ethan Gurwitz, and Andrew Schwartz

Market competition is faltering in some parts of the U.S. economy. Across many sectors, and across several decades, a significant share of corporations has been earning returns above competitive levels.

The expected response—entry of new firms that want to earn a share of those higher returns in those markets—has not happened. As a result, firm owners earn more, workers’ wages are lower, and incumbent firms have less pressure to innovate on their own.

These findings of returns that exceed competitive levels are an indication of entry barriers, and a new CAP report, “Toward a Robust Competition Policy,” tries to identify the sources of barriers.1 They include increased market concentration; the increased use of intellectual property protection in the form of patents; the rise of business models dependent on network externalities; and the rising importance of digital data as an input in production.

The report also identifies policies that can help to reduce barriers, including restricting acquisitions by firms protected by barriers; limiting the ability of such firms to enter adjacent markets; requiring the standardization and sharing of important data; and allowing users to communicate across digital platforms.

However, some markets may remain uncompetitive despite these policies. So this CAP report also advocates a monopoly tax designed to discourage the construction of entry barriers and to reduce the economic power that flows to individual companies from the presence of those barriers.

Significant numbers of corporations are earning monopoly-like profits

Measures commonly used by economists to evaluate firm-level economic performance now indicate that many firms have market power and are earning profits above competitive levels. For a significant number of firms, the ratio of market value to the replacement cost of its capital has risen well above one. In other words, investors are signaling that the expected returns of these firms exceed the current value of their combined assets. This is a recognized indicator that firms are able to extract economic rent—in other words, to earn returns beyond expected profits in a competitive market.

Figure 1 presents results from a large sample of publicly traded nonfinancial corporations showing that, for a significant fraction of firms, the ratio of market value to the replacement cost of firm capital has been above one and increasing since the late 1970s—an indication of monopoly-like profits.2

Sustained levels of monopoly-like profits are evidence of uncompetitive markets

Companies creating new breakthrough products or implementing more efficient processes that lowers costs or increases revenues should expect increasing profits. Under competitive markets, other companies seek to emulate or supplant competitors’ innovations. As a result, supply would increase, forcing down prices, and pushing down the innovating firm’s profits. Therefore, high profit levels should be temporary. Instead, corporations who have achieved excess profits in a given year are increasingly likely to maintain them in the subsequent year, as shown in Figure 2.

Monopoly-like profits are evident in many sectors of the U.S. economy, especially communications services, health care, and information technology

An analysis of the 200-largest companies in the sample across five-year periods going back to 1980, seen in Figure 3, indicates that the decades-long trend of increasing Q values occurs across sectors.

Additional indicators of reduced competition

  • The 90-50 ratio for corporate returns—the accounting return on invested capital for the 90th percentile of firms to the 50th percentile—has increased from around two in 1980 to around 10 in 2014.3
  • Corporate profits are concentrated in a declining number of firms. 4
  • Overall market concentration has increased over the past several decades.5
  • Rate of entry of new firms has been declining since the late 1970s.6
  • Rising concentration among employers is associated with job lock and weak wage growth.7

Barriers to entry limit the threat of new competitors

All of these indicators are compelling evidence suggesting that a significant number of firms have market power. This means that they have some ability to set the price for a good or service above competitive levels.

There are several factors—some old and some new—that help create, maintain, and enhance market power:

  • Mergers and acquisitions. Evidence shows that the increase in concentration following mergers reviewed by the antitrust agencies is too often accompanied by increased prices. Moreover, incumbent firms with market power have been allowed to use acquisitions to fend off potential competition.
  • Intellectual property protection. Tools such as patents are state-sanctioned monopolies intended to incentivize innovation. However, in recent decades, private actors have been able to earn patent rights based at least in part on discoveries from publicly funded research. In some industries, so-called patent thickets discourage new entrants.
  • Network effects. Some products—for instance, the telephone or social media platforms—become more valuable as more individuals use it. The benefits from this effect may be mitigated if consumers cannot easily switch to a competitor. Incompatibility among similar services leads to a lock-in effect and makes customers dependent on their current service.
  • Access to data. Companies across the digital economy have realized the value of data on the behavior and interests of users and customers. Firms with access to large amounts of data on individuals know more about their behavior and preferences and are better positioned to develop new machine learning and artificial intelligence tools. New entrants lack crucial inputs and are less likely to be able to compete in markets where these data are crucial.

Recommendations to decrease barriers to entry

  • Increase antitrust enforcement. Restrict acquisitions, particularly where existing entry barriers protect dominant companies. Limit operation in adjacent markets when entry could add to already significant barriers.
  • Change intellectual property policy. Shorten patents durations. Treat government as an early investor that can earn financial benefits when public investment is key to a profitable innovation. Increase public research budgets.
  • Formalize policies around data. Require data sharing and establish sharing requirements. Require that users can communicate across digital platforms. Require competition regulators to conduct merger reviews focusing on data and their impact.
  • Tax monopoly profits. When other policies cannot establish competitive market outcomes, establish a surtax on monopolistic profits. This can be accomplished without loss in efficiency.

Endnotes

  1. Marc Jarsulic, Ethan Gurwitz, and Andrew Schwartz, “Toward a Robust Competition Policy,” (Washington: Center for American Progress, 2019).
  2. Using firm-level data from a very large sample of publicly traded U.S. corporations for the period 1975–2015—excluding regulated utilities, financial firms, public service firms and some others—economists Ryan H. Peters and Lucian A. Taylor have constructed measures of firm-level Qs. These measures include the replacement cost of both tangible and intangible capital. The Figures in this Factsheet and in the paper it describes are based on Q data from this sample. The data are described in Ryan H. Peters and Lucian A. Taylor, “Intangible Capital and the Investment-q Relation,” Journal of Financial Economics 123 (2) (2017), available at https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X16301969.
  3. Jason Furman and Peter Orszag, “A Firm-Level Perspective on the Role of Rents in the Rise in Inequality: Presentation at ‘A Just Society’ Centennial Event in Honor of Joseph Stiglitz,” Columbia University, October 16, 2015, available at http://gabriel-zucman.eu/files/teaching/FurmanOrszag15.pdf.
  4. Aggregate corporate profits are at near-historic highs and are shared among fewer players. Kathleen Kahle and René Stulz found that, in 2015, just 30 public firms accounted for half of all public companies’ earnings compared with 109 firms in 1995. Additionally, just 35 public firms held half of all public corporate assets compared with 95 firms in 1975. See Lídia Brun and Ignacio González, “Tobin’s Q and Inequality” (2017), available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3069980; Kathleen M. Kahle and René M. Stulz, “Is the US Public Corporation in Trouble?”, Journal of Economic Perspective (2017), available at https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/jep.31.3.67.
  5. Gustavo Grullon, Yelena Larkin, and Roni Michaely examine several different measures pointing to “an increase in product market concentration over the past two decades.” See Gustavo Grullon, Yelena Larkin, and Roni Michaely, “Are U.S. Industries Becoming More Concentrated?”, Review of Finance (forthcoming), available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=2612047; David Autor and others, “Concentrating on the Fall of the Labor Share,” American Economic Review 107 (5) (2017), 180–185, available at https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aer.p20171102; Kahle and Stulz, “Is the US Public Corporation in Trouble?”.
  6. Since 1980, new firm entry has steadily declined by nearly half. Firms’ exit rates have also slowed, albeit less intensively, and today’s firms are, on average, older. See Ian Hathaway and Robert E. Litan, “What’s Driving the Decline in the Firm Formation Rate? A Partial Explanation” (Washington: Brookings Institution, 2014), available at https://www.brookings.edu/research/whats-driving-the-decline-in-the-firm-formation-rate-a-partial-explanation/; Ryan A. Decker and others, “Declining business dynamism: Implications for productivity?” (Washington: Brookings Institution, 2016), available at https://www.brookings.edu/research/declining-business-dynamism-implications-for-productivity/.
  7. Steven Davis and John Haltiwanger, “Labor Market Fluidity and Economic Performance,” (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2014) available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w20479; Simcha Barkai, “Declining labor and capital shares” (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago, 2016), available at http://home.uchicago.edu/~barkai/doc/BarkaiDecliningLaborCapital.pdf; Suresh Naidu, Eric A. Posner, and E. Glen Weyl, “Antitrust Remedies for Labor Market Power,” Harvard Law Review (forthcoming), available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3129221; Efraim Benmelech, Nittai Bergman, and Hyunseob Kim, “Strong Employers and Weak Employees: How Does Employer Concentration Affect Wages?” (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2018), available at https://www.nber.org/papers/w24307; José Azar, Ioana Marinescu, and Marshall I. Steinbaum, “Labor Market Concentration” (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2017), available at https://www.nber.org/papers/w24147.

The positions of American Progress, and our policy experts, are independent, and the findings and conclusions presented are those of American Progress alone. A full list of supporters is available here. American Progress would like to acknowledge the many generous supporters who make our work possible.

Authors

Marc Jarsulic

Senior Fellow; Chief Economist

Ethan Gurwitz

Policy Analyst

Andrew Schwartz

Senior Policy Analyst